by H Fessenden — In recent decades, asset speculation has driven sizeable boom-and-bust cycles in some of the world’s largest economies — cycles that have sometimes resulted
6 pages

131 KB – 6 Pages

PAGE – 1 ============
In recent decades, asset speculation has driven sizeable boom-and-bust cycles in some of the world™s largest economies Š cycles that have sometimes resulted in deep and persistent recessions. Two prominent examples of what are often termed fibubblesfl occurred in Japan in the 1990s and in the United States in the mid-to-late 2000s. In both cases, the bubbles began in real estate and coincided with a surging stock mar -ket. And in both cases, the ensuing recessions were severe, and in the case of Japan, especially long-standing. The size of these shocks has led to increased interest among economists and policymakers to ˜nd preventive tools to miti -gate the adverse impact of bubbles and the ˜nancial crises that can follow. The 2010 Dodd- Frank Act, for example, included provisions to strengthen fimacroprudentialfl oversight, that is, supervision and regulation that consider how individual ˜nancial institutions may a˚ect the ˜nancial system as a whole. Those changes have included more stringent capital require -ments and regular stress testing. April 2018, EB18-04Economic Brief EB18-04 – Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond The Roots of ‚Bubbly™ Recessions By Helen Fessenden and Toan Phan A downturn following the collapse of an asset bubble Š an episode of specu -lative booms in asset prices Š can be severe and sustained, with output and employment often lower than in the prebubble economy. This Economic Brief considers some possible theoretical explanations. It argues, based on insights from a simple economic model, that the interaction among ˜nancial frictions, wage rigidity, and the constraints of monetary policy near the zero lower bound is a key source of ine˚ciency in large bubbles. One potential remedy is to regulate speculative investment on bubbly assets so that indivi- dual investors internalize their investments™ e˛ects on systemic risk. Page 1 To understand potential policy implications, however, it™s critical to understand how bubbles emerge in the ˜rst place and how their collapse can lead to such deep downturns. A coauthor of this Economic Brief , Toan Phan, has analyzed this question through a simple and standard model of the macroeconomy, focusing on how a bubble™s collapse can contribute to particular economic ine˛ciencies. He argues that this out -come is due to a combination of market failure and speci˜c features of the modern economy. 1 The market failure takes the form of ˜nancial fifrictions,fl namely imperfections in the ˜nancial market that lead to constraints on borrowing. When such ˜nancial frictions coincide with a monetary policy that™s limited by very low interest rates, as well as the real-world tendency of employers to eschew sharp cuts in nominal wages, the result can be an especially harsh and enduring recession. The concept of ˜nancial frictions has a particular meaning in this context. In an ideal world, con –

PAGE – 2 ============
Page 2 sumers and ˜rms are able to borrow as much as they need. But in the real world, many factors can limit the amount of borrowing, including the amount of the borrower™s net worth. The greater the net worth, generally speaking, the more someone can borrow. The growth of a bubble can reduce these frictions by increasing the net worth of borrowers Š for exam -ple, through the value of commercial or residential real estate during a housing price boom. This Economic Brief explains how the combination of these factors can contribute to severe downturns, even if speculative investors are forward-looking and rational in the sense that they understand the bubble™s risk of collapse. The analysis also implies that macroprudential regulations on speculative investment during a bubble episode could reduce the severity of the postbubble recession. Indeed, some governments (for example, Vancouver, Canada, and China) are discussing or already experimenting with such measures in the context of certain types of regulations on housing investment, including taxes. Such measures could help reduce some of the ine˛ciencies associated with the bust, but they would come with a trade-o˚: to reduce the adverse consequences of a downturn, these levies also would have to scale back the economic growth of the preceding boom. The Upside of Bubbles The question of how bubbles form goes to a core issue of ˜nancial frictions. In an economy with rela -tively low interest rates, lenders earn only a modest return on their loans or investments. By contrast, speculation in a fibubbly assetfl Š where an investor buys an asset with the expectation that it can be sold later for a return that is possibly higher but riskier than the safe interest rate Š often may look like the more attractive option. Instead of putting one™s cash in a savings account to earn a low interest rate, for example, it may be tempting to put that money into a booming real estate market. However, such speculation is inherently risky because it requires a coordination of expectations or beliefs across inves -tors. That is, a speculator would invest in a bubbly asset only if he or she expected that someone else would buy that asset from them in the future, and in turn, the subsequent buyer would expect to be able to resell the asset, and so on. In a model economy with ˜nancial frictions, the boom of asset prices may then lead to a credit boom. As a bubbly asset appreciates, it enhances investors™ net worth, and higher net worth typically allows easier access to credit and higher credit limits. An uptick in borrowing then could lead to higher invest -ment and could ultimately boost credit, output, wages, and consumption. In this way, a bubble can encourage (or ficrowd infl) investment because rising investment is a result of rising net worth. 2 Indeed, this dynamic is roughly consistent with the boom in investment, employment, and other economic activ -ity during the Japanese and U.S. housing bubbles. (See Figure 1 on page 3 and Figure 2 on page 4.) What happens when such bubbles collapse? In theory, if only ˜nancial frictions were involved, the economy should shrink as borrowing would go back to normal, while wages would fall by a correspond -ing amount. This downturn would return the econ -omy and borrowing levels to their prebubble state and no further. But as some well-known real-world examples have suggested, the resulting recessions can leave everyone much worse o˚ than before the bubble began. How can this happen? The Downside of Bubbles In this model environment, severe postbubble reces – sions result from the combination of ˜nancial fric -tions and the particular e˚ects of downwardly rigid (or fistickyfl) wages and the constraints of monetary policy near the zero lower bound. Without rigidities, a ˜rm should be able to adjust wages up or down to re˝ect its workers™ marginal product of labor Š that is, the amount of output provided by each additional worker. In a downturn, ˜rms would like to cut down investment and production, leading to a reduction in the demand for labor. The drop in the demand for labor can result in either reduced wages or reduced employment. In practice, as has been well-docu – mented in history, nominal wages tend to not fall (thus the term fidownward wage rigidityfl); instead, employment falls. In other words, rather than cutting wages, ˜rms tend to lay o˚ workers or reduce their

PAGE – 3 ============
work hours, and unemployment rises. 3 At that point, a ˜rm has fewer workers and less capital, so its out -put declines, and the ˜rm™s owner sees a drop in net worth. Firms might borrow less and less, and capital stock might fall. Only when wages start, belatedly, to fall amid high unemployment will a ˜rm be willing to start hiring again. As a real-world example, it took about a decade in Japan for real and nominal wages to fall back to prerecession levels. Along with wage rigidity, low interest rates can exacerbate this type of downturn. When a central bank faces a recessionary environment, with falling employment and output, it typically would like to cut the nominal interest rate to stimulate demand. In a postbubble economy, however, there might be an excess of capital left over from the boom, in the sense there is not enough demand to utilize all of it. The excess capital leads to a low marginal product Page 3 of capital Š which, exacerbated by high unemploy -ment, puts more downward pressure on the return on capital and thus the real interest rate. A low real interest rate also implies a low nominal interest rate. Usually, the nominal interest rate is unlikely to fall below zero because a negative nominal interest rate can compel households and ˜rms to switch from deposits to holding cash. With su˛cient downward pressure, the nominal interest rate can be pushed against the zero lower bound. 4Economists refer to this scenario as a liquidity trap, in which a central bank is unable to reduce its monetary policy interest rate enough to stimulate output. Employment and investment might stay depressed, and in˝ation might be stuck below its target. As noted above, this was the case in 1990s Japan, which saw unemployment more than double while nominal and real wages stayed high. Similarly, Figure 1: Japan before and after the Collapse of Housing Prices and Stock Valuations Housing Price Index Nikkei Index GDP Per Capita Unemployment Rate 1990199019951995200020001980198019851985Sources: Data for these charts were retrieved from Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED) at the St. Louis Fed. GDP data are from the World Bank. Unemployment data and recession dates are from the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. Stock valuations are from the Nikkei Industry Research Institute. Housing prices are from the Dallas Fed as described in Adrienne Mack and Enrique Martínez-Garcia, fiA Cross-Country Quarterly Database of Real House Prices: A Methodological Note,fl Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Working Paper No. 99, December 2011. Notes: Dashed vertical lines indicate the approximate beginning of the collapse in asset prices (1991). Gray bars indicate recessions. 12010590 75 60 45 30 154238 34 30 26 221990 = 100 for Both Indexes Real GDP Per Capita in Thousands of 2010 U.S. Dollars Housing Prices and Stock Valuations Real GDP Per Capita and Unemployment Unemployment Rate 5.24.2 3.2 2.2 1.20.21.2 2.2 3.24.25.222 26 30343842Series3GDP per capita (1000s 2010USD)Unemployment Rate1530 45607590105120Nikkei IndexHousing Price Index

PAGE – 4 ============
Page 4 these cases, economists have tried to quantify the social costs of particular individual actions and rem -edy them through pricing schemes that, in turn, put the onus of the cost back on the responsible individu – al or ˜rm. 6 An example is tobacco, which causes such externalities as second-hand smoke and an extra burden on the health care system; taxing cigarettes can help individuals internalize the externalities of their own actions. In the case of bubbles, individual investors do not internalize the e˚ects of their investments on raising asset prices, which can produce an excessive boom that is followed by an ine˛cient bust. For example, a hedge fund is unlikely to internalize the fact that its speculative investment contributes to escalating real estate prices and that bigger booms are associated with deeper busts. Some of the risks associated with decisions made by investors to buy bubbly assets are, in this sense, borne by the population as a whole. By in the United States, unemployment jumped from 5 percent to 10 percent from 2007 to 2009 while real and nominal wages kept rising. In both cases, mon -etary policymakers cut nominal interest rates down to zero, but in˝ation stayed mired below prereces – sion levels. In recent years, some economists have argued that these and many other major economies might even be facing fisecular stagnationfl Š that is, a long-standing slowdown in growth and productivity independent of business cycles. 5Private Risk, Public Costs If the severity of postbubble recessions is caused by this mix of factors, what can policymakers do to pre -vent these scenarios in the future? One approach is to understand these downturns as producing negative fiexternalities,fl or the costs of an individual™s decision that others bear. There™s a rich literature in econom -ics on externalities, especially in areas such as tra˛c congestion, pollution, and tobacco consumption. In Figure 2: United States before and after the Collapse of Housing Prices and Stock Valuations Housing Price Index S&P 500 Index GDP Per Capita Unemployment Rate 2005200520102010201520151995199520002000Sources: Data for these charts were retrieved from Federal Reserve Economic Data (FRED) at the St. Louis Fed. GDP data are from the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis. Unemployment data are from the U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics. Recession dates are according to National Bureau of Economic Research. Stock valuations are from the S&P Dow Jones Indices. Housing data are from the Federal Housing Finance Agency Housing Price Index. Notes: Dashed vertical lines indicate the approximate beginning of the collapse in asset prices (2007). Gray bars indicate recessions. 170150 130 11090 70 50 305248 44 40 362000 = 100 for Both Indexes Real GDP Per Capita in Thousands of 2009 U.S. Dollars Housing Prices and Stock Valuations Real GDP Per Capita and Unemployment Unemployment Rate 1210 8 6 4 2 0024 6810123640444852Nov-94Nov-95Nov-96Nov-97Nov-98Nov-99Nov-00Nov-01Nov-02Nov-03Nov-04Nov-05Nov-06Nov-07Nov-08Nov-09Nov-10Nov-11Nov-12Nov-13Nov-14Real GDP Per CapitaUnemployment Rate305070901101301501701996.0031997.2521998.5001999.7492001.0052002.2512003.5002004.7512005.9972007.2512008.5022009.7502011.0072012.2532013.5012014.750S&P IndexHousing Price Index

PAGE – 5 ============
Page 5 extension, one way to price these externalities would be to impose a tax on investors as they speculate on bubbly assets. Such a tax would make them internal -ize the potential cost in the long run. A caveat is warranted. For the government to impose this levy, it would need to be able to identify and ob -serve the bubble ahead of its peak, which is a strong assumption. As former Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke noted in a 2010 speech that addressed asset bubbles and the Fed™s role, fiAlthough the house price bubble appears obvious in retrospect Š all bubbles appear obvious in retrospect Š in its ear -lier stages, economists di˚ered considerably about whether the increase in house prices was sustain – able; or, if it was a bubble, whether the bubble was national or con˜ned to a few local markets.fl 7But if the government does recognize the bubble and implements a levy, such a measure would mean that investors would adjust their demand for the as -set downward since the tax would make it more ex -pensive. The price of the bubbly asset would still rise but not as much as it would if left untaxed, and the risk would be better internalized among those inves -tors who could also reap the upside of the bubble. The trade-o˚ is that their net worth also would rise by less than it would without the tax, so the positive spillover e˚ect of greater borrowing on investment would also be somewhat muted. There are several recent cases where governments have considered a tax on bubbly assets. In China, for example, leaders have been increasingly concerned about the broader e˚ects of property speculation. (Many speculators buy apartments that remain unoc -cupied, and home prices in cities such as Shanghai and Beijing have soared.) In December 2016, for example, President Xi Jinping announced that the government would implement a mix of regulatory policies to better meet housing demand and control ˜nancial risk; at the Communist Party Congress this past March, he repeated that theme by noting that fihouses are built to be inhabited, not for specula – tion.fl O˛cials are now crafting a national property tax that could come into e˚ect next year. 8 Mean -while, in Vancouver, Canada, a 15 percent surcharge on real estate purchases, imposed in summer 2016, caused an immediate and sharp drop in home sales, including among the foreign buyers who have fa -vored the city as an investment destination. 9These examples point to the frequent role of the real estate sector in ˜nancial crises and show that poli -cymakers might be becoming more responsive to this link. 10 But as this Economic Brief explains, these boom-and-bust cycles can occur across sectors and have multiple drivers. Understanding the interaction of these factors can help policymakers develop tools to contain the costs of such episodes. Helen Fessenden is an economics writer and Toan Phan is an economist in the Research Department at the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond. Endnotes 1 This Economic Brief is based on the ˜ndings presented in a re -cent working paper published by the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond. See Siddhartha Biswas, Andrew Hanson, and Toan Phan, fi Bubbly Recessions ,fl Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Working Paper No. 18-05, February 22, 2018. Also, see Andrew Hanson and Toan Phan, fi Bubbles, Wage Rigidity, and Persistent Slumps,fl Economics Letters , February 2017, vol. 151, pp. 66Œ70. 2 For a discussion of how asset bubbles a˚ect growth amid ˜nancial frictions, see Tomohiro Hirano, and Noriyuki Yanagawa, fi Asset Bubbles, Endogenous Growth, and Finan -cial Frictions ,fl Review of Economic Studies , January 2017, vol. 84, no. 1, pp. 406Œ443. Also, see Alberto Martin and Jaume Ventura, fi Economic Growth with Bubbles ,fl American Economic Review, October 2012, vol. 102, no. 6, pp. 3033Œ3058, and Jianjun Miao and Pengfei Wang, fiAsset Bubbles and Credit Constraints,fl American Economic Review , forthcoming. 3 The evidence for downward nominal wage rigidity has been well-documented. See Takeshi Kimura and Kazuo Ueda, fiDownward Nominal Wage Rigidity in Japan ,fl Journal of the Japanese and International Economies , March 2001, vol. 15, no. 1, pp. 50Œ67. Also, see Steinar Holden and Fredrik Wulfs – berg, fi How Strong Is the Macroeconomic Case for Downward Real Wage Rigidity? fl Journal of Monetary Economics , May 2009, vol. 56, no. 4, pp. 605Œ615. A study of European wages can be found in Jan Babecký, Philip Du Caju, Theodora Kosma, Martina Lawless, Julián Messina, and Tairi Rõõm, fi Down ward Nominal and Real Wage Rigidity: Survey Evidence from Euro-pean Firms ,fl Scandinavian Journal of Economics , December 2010, vol. 112, no. 4, pp. 884Œ910. U.S. wages are analyzed in Mary Daly, Bart Hobijn, and Brian Lucking, fi Why Has Wage Growth Stayed Strong? fl Federal Reserve Bank of San Fran – cisco Economic Letter , April 2, 2012. 4 See also Stephanie Schmitt-Grohé and Martín Uribe, fi Liquid- ity Traps and Jobless Recoveries ,fl American Economic Journal:

PAGE – 6 ============
Macroeconomics , January 2017, vol. 9, no. 1, pp. 165Œ204. For a related discussion of the limits of monetary policy on bubbles and the role of the zero lower bound, see Vladimir Asriyan, Luca Fornaro, Alberto Martin, and Jaume Ventura, fi Monetary Policy for a Bubbly World ,fl National Bureau of Economic Re -search Working Paper No. 22639, September 2016. 5 See Gauti B. Eggertsson, Neil R. Mehrotra, and Lawrence H. Summers, fi Secular Stagnation in the Open Economy ,fl American Economic Review , May 2016, vol. 106, no. 5, pp. 503Œ507. 6 See Helen Fessenden, fi Pricing Vice ,fl Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Econ Focus , Second Quarter 2017, pp. 11Œ15. 7 Ben S. Bernanke, fi Monetary Policy and the Housing Bubble ,fl Speech at the Annual Meeting of the American Economic As – sociation, Atlanta, January 3, 2010. 8 See fi Xi Again Pledges to Curb Speculation in China Property Market ,fl Bloomberg News, December 21, 2016; fi Housing Should Be for Living in, Not for Speculation, Xi Says ,fl Bloom -berg News, October 18, 2017; and fi China Gets Closer to Game- Changing Property Tax ,fl Bloomberg News, March 7, 2018. 9 See Natalie Obiko Pearson, fi Foreign Buying Plummets in Vancouver after New Property Tax ,fl Bloomberg Markets, September 22, 2016. 10 As former Fed Vice Chairman Stanley Fischer noted in a speech in June 2017, fi[F]inancial crises can, and do, occur without a real estate crisis. But it is true that there is a strong link be -tween ˜nancial crises and di˛culties in the real estate sector.fl He added: fiThe drop in house prices in a bust is often bigger following credit-fueled housing booms, and recessions associ – ated with housing busts are two to three times more severe than other recessions. And, perhaps most signi˜cantly, real estate was at the center of the most recent crisis.fl He noted re -search ˜nding that there is a 59 percent to 67 percent chance of a recession following a credit and housing boom within three years, depending on how fiboomfl is de˜ned. Also, see Stijn Claessens, M. Ayhan Kose, and Marco E. Terrones, fi What Happens during Recessions, Crunches, and Busts? fl Economic Policy , October 2009, vol. 24, no. 60, pp. 653Œ700. Richmond Baltimore CharlotteFEDERAL RESERVE BANKOF RICHMONDPage 6 This article may be photocopied or reprinted in its entirety. Please credit the authors, source, and the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond and include the italicized statement below.Views expressed in this article are those of the authors and not necessarily those of the Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond or the Federal Reserve System.

131 KB – 6 Pages